Degussa | Wherever you look: Prices for consumer goods, real estate, stocks and bonds are on the rise. That means that the purchasing power of money is on the decline. For if, say, stock prices go up, your money unit can buy fewer stocks. What it also means is: While people holding assets, whose prices increase, become “richer”, people holding money get “poorer”. You may say: Why bother? Some people are smarter than others. They cleverly go into ‘real assets’ and refrain from holding money, while others are just too lazy and miss out on their fair chance to profit. One major problem with this kind of thinking is, however, that it ignores the objectionable root cause of generally rising prices: the fiat money system.
Fiat Money redistributes income and wealth
In today’s fiat money system, central banks, in close cooperation with commercial banks, relentlessly increase the quantity of money through credit expansion. That is, they extend credit and thereby issue new money, created out of thin air, money that is not backed by real savings. The first receivers of the new money are of course the beneficiaries: They can exchange their new money against goods and services at unchanged prices. As the new money is passed on from hand to hand, so to say, the demand for vendible items goes up, translating into higher goods prices. The late receivers of the new money can only buy at already elevated prices. As a result, income and wealth of the early receivers of the new money go up at the expense of the late receivers of the new money – let alone all those people who do not gain anything from the increase in the money supply. The issuance of fiat money creates winners and losers. It is unlike what happens in a genuinely free market, in which people trade voluntarily with one another, and both parties benefit from such a transaction. In a fiat money regime, in contrast, it is the early receivers of the new money that reap a “windfall profit”, which comes at the expense of all those who come later in line. As things stand, there is no escape from this coercive redistribution of income and wealth – as governments have monopolised money production. People have to use the governments’ fiat money. ‘Alternative money candidates’ have either been outlawed or made uncompetitive by legal tender laws and or subjecting them to capital gain tax and/or VAT. The issuance of fiat money cannot be, and is not meant to be, beneficial for all but is made to favour some at the expense of others. In general, those who have easy access to bank credit clearly belong to those who benefit: The governments, commercial and investment banks, big business, the financial industry at large. The disadvantaged are, generally speaking, those groups who do a kind of business that is actually quite remote from central banks’ and commercial banks’ money production: Businesses that do not receive orders and contracts from the group of the early receivers of the new money, including, of course, their employees.
Misleading definition of inflation
In recent years, mainstream economics has been arguing that inflation is actually a rise in consumer goods prices by more than 2 per cent per year, and many people seem to buy this story. However, it is a rather misleading, deceptive conceptualisation of the ‘inflation phenomenon’ for various reasons. The increase in fiat money does not only show up in consumer goods prices, but it also affects ‘asset prices’: the prices of, say, stocks, bonds, real estate, art, etc. In the last decades, central banks’ inflationary policies have shown up predominantly in rising asset prices and not in overly sharp increases in consumer prices. It should be clear, however, that a rise in asset prices erodes the purchasing power of money just as effectively as does an increase in consumer goods prices. Nevertheless, central banks, with the intellectual support of mainstream economics, defend the idea of measuring inflation by changes in consumer goods prices but not asset prices. There is good reason to believe that the actual loss in purchasing power of money is (much) higher than is suggested by consumer goods price statistics. For instance, in the period 2000 to 2019, the US dollar (if and when kept as cash) has lost 35% of its purchasing power compared to consumer goods prices. In the same period, it has lost 53% of its purchasing power in terms of housing. In other words: People have to spend more than double the amount of money for a house today compared to 20 years ago (other things being equal), or they have to save twice as long or borrow twice as much as two decades ago.
Boom and bust
An additional consequence of the issuance of fiat money is the artificial boom is sets into motion. The increase of credit supply not backed by real savings pushes the market interest rate down to an artificially low level. This, in turn, discourages savings, increases consumption, and it also fuels additional investment. The painful news is that the boom brings overconsumption and malinvestment. People live beyond their means. They consume more and save less – compared with a situation in which the market interest rate had not been artificially lowered. Firms engage in investments which, under ‘unhampered market conditions’, are actually not profitable. However, as long as the market interest rates remain artificially lowered by injections of fiat money issued through credit expansion, the boom is upheld. If the inflow of additional credit and money dries up, however, and the market interest rate returns to its ‘normal level’, the boom will turn into bust. People enjoy the boom, and they loathe the bust. So, once they have initiated the boom, central banks can count on support from politicians, banks, industrial firms, unions, employees, and even pensioners to take all kinds of measures to keep the boom going because no one wants to pay the bill run up by the boom. As a result, the central bank brings interest rates to ever lower levels and pumps ever more credit and money into the system to keep the boom going. The chances are that under such a policy, the deceptive economic expansion can be kept going for a while. But it will take ever more ‘aggressive measures’ to keep it going.
It does not take much to understand what this ‘corrupt incentive structure’ brings: Central banks will keep inflating. In the first step, they will try to keep inflating asset prices – as it supports the boom and they get away with it: People do not complain about ‘asset price inflation’, and they do not blame central banks’ monetary policies for it. That said, the lesson to learn is this: Fiat money – be it US dollar, euro, Chinese renminbi, British Pound, Swiss Franc, etc. – will most likely continue to lose its purchasing power over time. Some perhaps faster, some maybe less quickly. But people should be aware that fiat money is no reliable store of value. There might be a point in time when the fiat money system crashes altogether – for inflation is a policy that cannot last. However, we do not know when the death knell of the fiat money regime will ring. That said, the minimum advice is this: Do not entrust your life savings to fiat currency; and do not expect the crash too soon.